The relationship between a country’s economic characteristics and its fragility and susceptibility to conflict is complex and mutually reinforcing (See Holden and Pagel 2012). Collier (2009) identify three related causal paths: opportunity (or ‘greed’), grievance, and feasibility. This framework is generally considered to be useful for conceptualising the relationship between fragility and economic development. However, there is a lack of consensus as to which is the most influential factor during various phases of conflict at the macro, meso and micro levels. , Moving beyond distinguishing between these causal factors Collier & Hoeffler (2002), Keen (2001) and Cramer 2002 emphasise the importance of considering how they interact with one another. In particular how greed might emerge from grievances and how the greedy may manipulate the grievances of others.
This section focuses on the three main strands in the literature: the influence of economic development on fragility and the susceptibility to violent conflict; the mutually reinforcing nature of continued fragility/conflict and its associated economic characteristics; and the effects of a legacy of conflict/fragility on economic development. Of course, the fluid nature of fragility and conflict cannot be adequately captured by this structure.
Susceptibility to conflict
Macro-level
Some of the key debates regarding the relationship between macro-level economic development and susceptibility to conflict focus on:
- levels of per capita income and economic growth;
- different types of economic growth;
- the mitigating and exacerbating characteristics of trade;
- the overarching role that gender plays in this relationship.
Much of the work on economic development and conflict is driven by Collier and Hoeffler’s work associating high per capita incomes and economic growth with a reduced likelihood of conflict (2003). An analysis of a global sample of civil wars between 1965 and 2004 corroborates this. Collier et al (2009) find that economic growth for conflict-affected countries averaged -0.5 per cent in the five years before the onset of conflict, relative to 2 per cent in peaceful countries. However, these findings do not explain the causal mechanisms at play in contexts where conflict occurred during periods of general growth, or where pockets of fragility prevail in countries with high growth rates, as is the case in Sri Lanka (Ganegodage and Rambaldi 2014) and Nigeria, respectively.
Miguel et al. (2004) find that economic growth has a strong negative relation to civil conflict. They use rainfall as an instrumental variable for economic growth to examine the relationship between economic growth and conflict for 41 African countries between 1981 and 1999. The authors argue that rainfall is an important determinant of economic shocks, and thus GDP growth, in the countries studied because they remain largely dependent on rain-fed agriculture. Ciccone (2011) critiques this approach, arguing that annual changes in rainfall should not be used for two reasons: because of their mean-reverting nature, and because the relationship between rainfall shocks and economic growth loses significance in the countries studied after 1999.
Dal Bó and Dal Bó (2011) also challenge the conclusions of Miguel et al. (2004), suggesting that not all economic growth reduces conflict. Different types of economic shocks can have divergent impacts. They theorise that while positive shocks to labour intensive economic activities can decrease social conflict, positive shocks to capital intensive activities can increase it. This theory is supported by Dube and Vargas’s investigation into the conflict effects of global price shocks on coffee (labour intensive) and oil (non-labour intensive) in Colombia (2013). They find more inclusive growth in labour intensive commodities: reducing grievances; increasing the opportunity cost of engaging in violence; and making it less feasible for warring factions to recruit. Growth in non-labour intensive commodities, however, may produce narrow growth and exacerbate inequalities, creating opportunities for appropriation, and providing financing that makes war more feasible.
These findings suggest that attention should be paid to the different mechanisms through which economic growth influences conflict risk. Blattman and Annan (2014), however, challenge the findings of all four of these studies, suggesting that there are limits to testing theories of individual behaviour with macro-level data. Income shocks could also affect conflict and crime by lowering police and military capacity, by affecting the recruitment strategies and incentives of armed groups, or by inducing migration or increasing tension over limited resources, such as water.
While there is debate over its impact on fragility and conflict, openness to trade has been identified as one way in which economic shocks can be exacerbated or mitigated. Hegre et al. (2002) find suggestive evidence that trade has beneficial effects on growth and political stability. They find economic openness to be associated with higher growth, and although this growth may increase income inequality, this inequality is not associated with civil war. However, Brückner and Ciccone (2010) show that negative global commodity price shocks were associated with increased likelihood of conflict.
Gender has emerged as a prominent factor in sustaining economic growth, reducing poverty and increasing development effectiveness (Fennel 2009). Gender equality and the empowerment of women are important for a number of reasons— fairness, equality of opportunity, and economic well-being. Increasing efficiency and achieving the full potential of men and women alike is a precursor to prosperity (World Bank 2007). Studies have found that there is a relationship between the physical security of women and the relative peacefulness of states (Hudson et al. 2008:35), and that there is a correlation between levels of conflict and gender inequality (Hudson et al. 2012; Institute for Economics and Peace 2013).
Meso-level
The issues and theories related to meso-level economic characteristics and conflict risk cover the:
- adverse effects of corruption and mismanagement, particularly with regards to natural resource management;
- role of the financial sector and of foreign direct investment (FDI) in mitigating or exacerbating conflict risk.
Ballentine and Haufler (2009) argue that corruption and mismanagement in business, particularly in relation to natural resources and large infrastructure projects, can exacerbate conflict risk. Contracting processes provide opportunities for mismanagement in a way that enriches a few at the expense of many, creating severe divisions. Similarly, the creation of modern industry can exacerbate existing grievances among competing groups by creating new winners and losers. Putzel and Di John (2012) link these issues to political settlements, claiming that where informal, sometimes illegal, activities provide opportunities for violent entrepreneurs to build and sustain power; this may result in an unconsolidated elite bargain, making the state very fragile.
The role of extractive resources in fuelling and financing conflict is highlighted by the UNEP et al. (2013), which gives the examples of the Democratic Republic of the Congo’s untapped mineral reserves and Afghanistan’s mineral deposits. Resource rich countries have been found to be at a higher risk of civil war and of encountering greater impediments to achieving both an early resolution of conflict and a peace that holds (Pally 2003 in UNDP 2008). Ross (2003) finds that civil wars are influenced by three characteristics of natural resources: lootability, obstructability and legality. While these authors do not debate the relationship between natural resources and conflict, they illustrate a need for more focus on the interaction between different types of natural resources and the context.
Ganesan and Vines (2004) find that whilst the nexus between resources, revenues, and civil war is critically important, a missing element of greed vs. grievance theory is the role that governments of resource-rich states play. They specify three ways in which elite capture by government can exacerbate conflict:
- control over resources gives such governments a strong incentive to maintain power, even at the expense of public welfare and the rights of the population (“Predatory Autocracies” e.g. the government of Angola which was largely dependent on oil during the latter years of its war with UNITA).
- unaccountable governments with large revenue streams at their disposal have multiple opportunities to divert funds for illegal purposes (e.g. the Liberian government under Charles Taylor).
- actions of third-party governments seeking to profit from resource-rich neighbours (e.g. the intervention of the Ugandan and Rwandan governments in the conflict in DRC, a conflict that itself has been impelled by competition for lucrative resources).
Barma et al. (2012) propose a two dimensional typology to help development practitioners identify a resource-dependent country’s political economy trajectory. First is the degree to which, over time, policy stability and bargains can be enforced and deviations sanctioned. Second is the overall political inclusiveness of prevailing state-society relations, including a sense of whether collectivist or clientelist welfare is privileged over purely elite interests.
Addison et al. (2001) focus specifically on the relationship between a country’s financial sector and the occurrence and resolution of conflict. Narrow development, which is at the root of conflict, is often financed in a way that exacerbates grievances. They identify three processes through which this occurs:
- in agrarian societies with high income- and land- inequality, agrarian elites may use their control within the financial system to further leverage their existing wealth, exacerbating inequalities.
- state banking systems may be used to finance private accumulation rather than investment, leading to economic decline and potentially conflict if the bank collapses under bad loans.
- weak financial regulation may facilitate the accumulation of wealth by means of fraud, destroying savings and living standards and increasing the risk of conflict.
Evidence on the relationship between FDI and conflict remains inconclusive (EC 2009). While Polachek et al. (2012) find that trade and FDI complement each other in reducing conflict risk, Gissinger and Gleditsch (1999) point out that despite its positive effects on economic welfare, FDI can generate grievances through its adverse effects on distribution and political unrest in poor countries. Alternatively, Barbieri and Reuveny (2005) find that FDI in the least developed countries reduces the duration of civil wars but not the likelihood of their onset. These opposing arguments might be reconciled by the recognition that overcoming state fragility and building strong institutions, as well as developing regulation to promote quality investments, are important to capture the economic and conflict-reducing benefits of FDI. Massa and te Velde (2011) suggest that development finance institutions can play a role in catalysing FDI that is beneficial in fragile contexts, providing important demonstration effects for other investors with regards to investment in higher-risk context (Dalberg Global Development Advisors 2010).
Micro-level
The literature on the influence of microeconomic characteristics on conflict risk focuses on the:
- mechanisms through which economic development might affect conflict (opportunity, grievance, feasibility);
- role of economic inclusion irrespective of average economic conditions.
Growth can stimulate job creation, which reduces grievances and incentives to engage in conflict (Collier, et al. 2009). In Afghanistan and Pakistan, the US Department of State (2010) described job creation as key to undermining the appeal of extremists in the short-term and necessary for sustainable economic growth in the long-term.
However, micro-level assumptions connecting unemployment to increased conflict risk (Berman et al. 2011) are debated. Using survey data from Afghanistan, Iraq and the Philippines, Berman et al. (2011) find no evidence that employed young men are less likely to participate in political violence. They suggest two plausible explanations: as local economic conditions deteriorate, government allies are able to gather intelligence at a lower cost; and that efforts to enhance security tend to damage the economy. Other studies of criminal and revolutionary organisations, such as Levitt and Venkatesh (2000), cast further doubt on the opportunity-cost approach, suggesting that status and future prospects for future riches and power, rather than wages, are the primary economic motivations. Mercy Corps’ (2015) research on the key drivers of youth’s propensity toward political violence in Sub-Saharan Africa finds that in most countries an individual’s employment status has very little effect on participation in, or willingness to participate in violence. Other factors related to government institutions and poverty levels were more important and relevant across contexts.
Growth may determine government popularity, influencing grievances and the willingness of the population to sympathise with a particular side (Collier, et al. 2009). Institutional breakdown and a failure of the social contract are often associated with poverty and growth failure (Murshed & Tadjoeddin, 2009). Alternatively, Fearon and Laitin (2003) claim that low or falling national income can weaken or signal weak central government, hindering the ability of governments and their militaries to repress insurgencies. Each of these mechanisms generally make it easier for armed militia groups to recruit fighters (Miguel, et al. 2004), making conflict feasible.
Collier et al. (2009) argue that financial and military feasibility is the key determinant of whether a rebellion will occur. Specifically, they argue that natural resources, when predated by rebels, can finance the escalation and sustainability of rebellion. However, they also acknowledge that the presence of natural resources might provide motivation for rebels to capture the rents both during and after a conflict, or that grievances in resource-rich countries may be stronger if the governments of these countries do not need to tax their citizens as much and are therefore less responsive.
This research faces strong criticism. Nathan (2005) identifies multiple empirical, methodological and theoretical issues in its analysis including the use of inappropriate proxies; unsubstantiated explanations of results; incomplete, inaccurate and biased data; and theoretical and analytical flaws. Similarly, Cramer (2002) criticises the feasibility argument, arguing that the method of paying for a war should not be confused with its cause; natural resources played a crucial role in the eastern DRC conflict, but the conflict’s origins had connections to the aftermath of the Rwandan war and genocide, as well as the collapse of Mobutu’s domination of Zaire. The interaction between financial incentives and long-standing ethnic, political and regional tensions also play a role. Klare (2001) argues that grievances as a result of governments exploiting resources occupied by a particular indigenous group are most likely to occur in developing countries with few sources of wealth, and weak and divided governments that are perceived as corrupt.
Lack of inclusion in growth is considered a risk to conflict, particularly where there are horizontal inequalities related to regional or ethnic disadvantage (Stewart 2010). Horizontal inequalities may motivate not only deprived groups, but also relatively privileged groups who wish to protect their share of resources. Ostby (2008) confirms this hypothesis through an analysis across 55 countries from 1986-2003. She finds that countries with severe economic and social horizontal inequalities, measured by average household assets and average years of education, faced a significantly higher probability of conflict. Horizontal inequalities between ethnic groups can also promote ethno-nationalist conflict. Ethnic groups determined to be either affluent or poor relative to the national average are both more likely to engage in conflict (Cederman et al. 2011).
The theories presented on the origins of conflict and how they relate to economic development remain incomplete and untested. Blattman and Miguel (2010) point out that the literature rarely considers alternatives to purely rational theories. Cramer (2002) debates the usefulness of analysis resulting from rational choice theories of armed conflict, arguing that they ignore a range of social, cultural and historical factors and violate the complexity of individual motivations. Nathan (2005) specifically criticises the influential work of Collier and Hoeffler for failing to adequately address politics and history.
- Abdelnour, S., Badri, B., El Jack, A., Wheeler, D., McGrath, S., & Branzei, O. (2008). Examining enterprise capacity: A participatory social assessment in Darfur and Southern Sudan. York: University Centre for Refugee Studies See document online
- Abrahams, N. & Jewkes, R. (2005). Effects of South African men’s having witnessed abuse of their mothers during childhood on their levels of violence in adulthood. American Journal of Public Health, 95(10). See document online
- Adam, C., Collier, P., & Davies, V. (2008). Post-conflict monetary reconstruction. World Bank Economic Review, 22(1), 87-112. See document online
- Adam, J. (2008). Displacement, coping mechanisms and the emergence of new markets in Ambon (CRG Working paper 9). Ghent: Conflict Research Group See document online
- Addison, T., Le Billon, P., & Murshed, S. M. (2001). Finance in conflict and reconstruction (WIDER Discussion Paper No. 2001/44). Helsinki: UNU/WIDER. See document online
- Conflict Sensitivity Consortium. (2004). Conflict-sensitive approaches to development, humanitarian assistance and peacebuilding: Resource pack. London: Conflict Sensitivity Consortium. See document online
- Alinovi, L., Hemrich, G., & Russo, L. (2007). Addressing food insecurity in fragile states: Case studies from the Democratic Republic of the Congo, Somalia and Sudan (ESA Working Paper 07-21). Rome: Food and Agriculture OrganizationSee document online
- Anand, P. (2005). Getting infrastructure priorities right in post-conflict reconstruction (UNU-WIDER Research Paper 2005/42). Helsinki: UN-WIDER. See document online
- Annan, J., Blattman, C., & Horton, R. (2006). The state of youth and youth protection in Northern Uganda: Findings from the Survey for War Affected Youth. Kampala: UNICEF Uganda. See document online
- Ballentine, K., & Haufler, V. (2009). Enabling economies of peace: Public policy for conflict-sensitive business. New York: United Nations Global Compact. See document online
- Banfield, J., Gündüz, C. & Killick, N. (Eds.). (2006). Local business, local peace: The peacebuilding potential of the domestic private sector. London: International Alert. See document online
- Barbieri, K. & Reuveny, R. (2005). Economic globalization and civil war. The Journal of Politics, 67(4), 1228-1247. See document online
- Barma, N. H., Kaiser, K., Le, T. M. & Viñuela, L. (2012). Rents to riches? The political economy of natural resource-led development. Washington, DC: World Bank. See document online
- Bastick, M., Grimm, K. & Kunz, R. (2007). Sexual violence in armed conflict: Global overview and implications for the security sector. Geneva: Centre for the Democratic Control of Armed Forces. See document online
- Bayne, S. and T. Vaux (2013). ‘Integrated development and peacebuilding programming: Design, monitoring and evaluation’, DFID.
- Beall, J., & Schutte, S. (2006). Urban livelihoods in Afghanistan (Synthesis paper series). Kabul: AREU. See document online
- Beasley, K. W. (2006). Job creation in postconflict societies. USAID. See document online
- Bellows, J., & Miguel, E. (2009). War and local collective action in Sierra Leone. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 1144–57. See document online
- Berman, E., Felter, J. H., Shapiro, J. N., & Callen, M. (2011). Do working men rebel? Insurgency and unemployment in Afghanistan, Iraq and the Philippines. Journal of conflict Resolutions, 55(4), 496-528. See document online
- Blattman, C., & Miguel, E. (2010). Civil war. Journal of Economic Literature, 48(1), 3-57. See document online
- Blattman, C. & Annan, J. (2014). Can employment reduce lawlessness and rebellion? A field experiment with high-risk men in a fragile state (NBER Working Paper No. 21289). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. See document online
- Bray, J. (2007). The role of private-sector development in post-conflict recovery. UNDP. See document online
- Brown, O. (2013). Encouraging peace-building through better environmental and natural resource management (Energy, environment and resources briefing paper EER BP 2013/04). London: Chatham House See document online
- Brück, T., & Schindler, K. (2008). The impact of conflict on households: A conceptual framework with reference to widows (WIDER research paper 2008/83). Helsinki: UNU-WIDER. See document online
- Brückner, M., & Ciccone, A. (2010). International commodity prices, growth and the outbreak of civil war in Sub-Saharan Africa. The Economic Journal, 120(544), 519–534. See document online
- Buchanan-Smith, M., & Fadul, A. A. (2008). Adaptation and devastation: The impact of the conflict on trade and markets in Darfur. Medford, MA: Feinstein International Centre. See document online
- Byrne, B. (1996). Gender, conflict and development: Vol. 1. Overview (BRIDGE Report No. 34, Rev. ed.). Brighton: Institute of Development Studies. See document online
- Carnahan, M., Durch, W., & Gilmore, S. (2006). Economic impact of peacekeeping. New York: United Nations. See document online
- Castillejo, C. (2011). Building a state that works for women: Integrating gender into post-conflict state building (Working paper no. 107). Madrid: FRIDE. See document online
- Castillejo, C. (2014). Promoting inclusion in political settlements: a priority for international actors? Norweigan Peacekeeping Resource Centre.
- Cederman, L. E., Weidman, N. B., & Gleditsch, K.S. (2011). Horizontal inequalities and ethno-nationalist civil war: A global comparison. American Political Science Review, 105(3), 478-495. See document online
- Cerise, S. and F. Francavilla (2012). Tackling the root causes of gender inequalities in the post-2015 development agenda (The Heart of the Post-2015 Development Agenda and the Future We Want for All, Global Thematic Consultation). New York: United Nations. See document online
- Chamarbagwala, R., & Moran, H.E. (2011). The human capital consequence of civil war: Evidence from Guatemala. Journal of Development Economics, 94(1), 41-61. See document online
- Channell, W. (2010). Peacebuilding essentials for economic development practitioners practice note 2: Business environment reforms in conflict-affected contexts (Strengthening the economic dimensions of peacebuilding practice note series). International Alert. See document online
- Chauvet, L., & Collier, P. (2008). What are the preconditions for turnarounds in failing states? Conflict Management and Peace Science, 25(4), 332-348. See document online
- Christian, S., de Janvry, A., Egel, D., & Sadoulet, E. (2013). Quantitative evaluation of the Social Fund for Development labor intensive works program (LIWP). Sana’a: Yemen Social Fund for Development. See document online
- Ciccone, A. (2011). Economic shocks and civil conflict: A comment. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 3, 215-227 See document online
- Collier, P. (1999). On the economic consequences of civil war. Oxford Economic Papers, 51 (1), 168-183 See document online
- Collier, P. (2006). Post-conflict economic recovery. New York: International Peace Academy. See document online
- Collier, P. (2009). Post-conflict recovery: How should strategies be distinctive? Journal of African Economies, 18(supplement 1), i99-i131. See document online
- Collier, P., & Duponchel, M. (2010). The economic legacy of civil war: Firm level evidence from Sierra Leone (Working paper no. 2010/90). Helsinki: UNU/WIDER. See document online
- Collier, P., & Hoeffler, A. (2002). Aid, policy and peace: Reducing the risks of civil conflict. Defence and Peace Economics, 13(6), 435-50. See document online
- Collier, P., & Hoeffler, A. (2007). Civil war. In T. Sandler & K. Hartley (Eds.) Handbook of Defence Economics (Vol. 2, 711-39). Amsterdam: North-Holland. See document online
- Collier, P., Hoeffler, A., & Rohner, D. (2009). Beyond greed and grievance: Feasibility and civil war. Oxford Economic Papers, 61(1), 1-27. See document online
- Collier, P., Hoeffler, A., & Söderbom, M. (2004). On the duration of civil war. Journal of Peace Research, 41(3), 253-273. See document online
- Collier, P., Hoeffler, A., & Söderbom, M. (2008). Post-conflict risks. Journal of Peace Research, 45(4), 461-478. See document online
- Cooper, N. (2002). State collapse as business: the role of conflict trade and the emerging control agenda. Development and Change, 33(5), 935-955 See document online
- Corlazzoli, V. (2014). ICTs for monitoring and evaluation of peacebuilding programmes. London: DFID. See document online
- Corlazzoli, V., & White, J. (2013a). Back to basics: A compilation of best practices in design, monitoring & evaluation in fragile and conflict-affected environments. London: DFID. See document online
- Corlazzoli, V., & White, J. (2013b). Measuring the un-measurable: Solutions to measurement challenges in fragile and conflict-affected environments. London: DFID. See document online
- Cramer, C. (2002). Homo economicus goes to war: Methodological individualism, rational choice and the political economy of war. World Development, 30(11), 1845-1864. See document online
- Curtis, L., Davis, P., Gündüz, C., Ockenden, A., Pedrick, T., Vaux, T., & Van Der Zwan, J. (2010). Private sector development in conflict-affected environments: Key resources for practitioners. Cambridge: The Donor Committee for Enterprise Development. See document online
- Dalberg Global Development Advisors. (2010). The growing role of the development finance institutions in international development policy. Copenhagen: Dalberg Global Development Advisors. See document online
- Darby, S. (2010). ‘Natural resource governance New frontiers in transparency and accountability’. Open Society Foundation
- Datzberger, S., & Denison, M. (2013). Private sector development in fragile states (EPS PEAKS Helpdesk Request). London: EPS PEAKS. See document online
- David, A., Rodrigues Bastos, F., & Mills, M. (2011). Post-conflict recovery: Institutions, aid or luck? (Working paper no. 11/149). Washington, DC: IMF. See document online
- Davis, P. (2011). The political economy of business environment reform: An introduction for practitioners. Cambridge: The Donor Committee for Enterprise Development. See document online
- DCED. (2008).Supporting business environment reforms: Practical guidance for development agencies. Cambridge: The Donor Committee for Enterprise Development. See document online
- De Vries, H., & Specker, L. (2009). Early economic recovery in fragile states: Priority areas and operational challenges. The Hague: Clingendael Institute. See document online
- Delechat, C., Clark, W., Gupta, P., Kabedi-Mbuyi, P., Koulet-Vickot, M., Macario, C., … Yang., S. (2015). Harnessing resource wealth for inclusive growth in fragile states (Working paper no. 15/25). Washington, DC: IMF. See document online
- DeLoach, S. B.,& Lamanna, E. (2011). Measuring the impact of microfinance on child health outcomes in Indonesia. World Development, 39(10), 1808–19. See document online
- Department of State. (2010). Afghanistan and Pakistan regional stabilization strategy. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office. See document online
- DFID. (2005). Why we need to work more effectively in fragile states. London: DFID. See document online
- DFID. (2010). Systematic reviews and evidence informed policy-making: Overview. London: DFID. See document online
- DFID. (2010). Building peaceful states and societies: A Practice Paper. London: DFID. See document online
- DFID. (2012). Supporting infrastructure development in FCAS: Case study – DR Congo. London: DFID See document online
- DFID. (2012). Results in fragile and conflict-affected states and situations (How-to note). London: DFID. See document online
- DFID. (2013). Strengthening the agriculture sector in Afghanistan (SASA): Annual Review. London: DFID. See document online
- DFID. (2014a). Economic development for shared prosperity and poverty reduction: a strategic framework. London: DFID. See document online
- DFID. (2014b). Afghanistan Investment Climate Facility (AICF): Annual review. London: DFID. See document online
- DFID. (2014c). Annual review – Summary sheet: Sustainable employment and economic development programme II (SEED II). London: DFID. See document online
- DFID. (2014d). Rural and agricultural markets development programme for Northern Nigeria (Propcom Mai-karfi): Annual review. London: DFID. See document online
- Di John, J. & Putzel, J. (2009). Political Settlements (GSDRC Issues Paper). Birmingham: GSDRC. See document online
- Dietsche, E., Dodd, S., Haglund, D., Henstridge, M,. Jakobsen, M.,Sindou, E., & Slaven., C. (2013).Extractives industries, development and the role of donors. Topic Guide. London: EPS PEAKS.
- Domingo, P., Holmes, R., Rocha Menocal, A., & Jones, N. (with Bhuvanendra, D. & Wood, J.).(2013). Assessment of the evidence of links between gender equality, peacebuilding and statebuilding: Literature review. London: ODI. See document online
- Dube, O., & Vargas, J. F. (2013). Commodity price shocks and civil conflict: Evidence from Colombia/ Review of Economic Studies, 80(4), 1384-1421. See document online
- European Commission. (2009). Overcoming fragility in Africa (European Report on Development). European Communities. See document online
- Eisendrath, A. (2007). Use of operating contracts for managing infrastructure enterprises under ‘difficult’ conditions. Washington, DC: USAID. See document online
- EITI. (2010). Impact of EITI in Africa. Stories from the ground. Oslo: EITI. See document online
- El-Bushra, J. (with Adrian-Paul, A., & Olson, M.). (2003). Women building peace: Sharing know-how. London: International Alert. See document online
- Erskine, W., & Nesbitt, H. (2009). How can agriculture research make a difference in countries emerging from conflict? Experimental Agriculture, 45(03), 313-321. See document online
- Fearon, J.,& Laitin, D. (2003). Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war. American Political Science Review, 97(1). See document online
- Fennel, S. (2009). A literature review on the gender indicator in the Country Policy and Institutional Assessment. Washington, DC: World Bank.
- Foltz, J. D., & Opoku-Agyemang, K. A. (2011). Low-intensity conflict and schooling outcomes: Evidence from Uganda. See document online
- Ford, J. (2015). Regulating business for peace: The United Nations, the private sector, and post-conflict recovery. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. See document online
- Frances, P., Lapin, D., & Rossiasco, P. (2011). Securing development and peace in the Niger Delta. A social and conflict analysis for change. Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars. See document online
- Friedemann-Sánchez, G. (2006) Assets in intrahousehold bargaining among women workers in Colombia’s cut-flower industry. Feminist Economics, 12(1-2), 247-269. See document online
- Gallagher, E. (2009). Outcome evaluation of the UNDP/PAPP mid-term strategic framework, 2008-2011: Final report. New York: UNDP. See document online
- Ganegodage, K. R., & Rambaldi, A. N. (2014). Economic consequences of war: Evidence from Sri Lanka. Journal of Asian Economics, 30, 42-53. See document online
- Ganesan, A., & Vines, A. (2004). Engine of war: Resources, greed and the predatory state. In Human rights and armed conflict: Human Rights Watch world report 2004. New York: Human Rights Watch. See document online
- Gates, S, Hegre, H., Nygard, H. M., & Strand, H. (2012). Development consequences of armed conflict. World Development, 40(9), 1713-1722 See document online
- Gerstle, T., & Meissner, L. (2010). Market development in conflict-affected contexts (Strengthening the economic dimensions of peacebuilding practice note 1). International Alert. See document online
- Gissinger, R., & Gleditsch, N. L. (1999). Globalization and conflict: Welfare, distribution, and political unrest. Journal of World-Systems Research, 5(2), 327-365. See document online
- Goldstein, J. S. (2001). War and gender: how gender shapes the war system and vice versa. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
- Goldwyn, R., & Chigas, D. (2013). Monitoring and evaluating conflict sensitivity: Methodological challenges and practical solutions. London: DFID. See document online
- Goodhand, J. (2008). Corrupting or consolidating the peace? The drugs economy and post-conflict peacebuilding in Afghanistan. International Peacekeeping, 15(3), 405–23. See document online
- Goodhand, J. (2004). From war economy to peace economy? Reconstruction and state Building in Afghanistan. Journal of International Affairs, 58(1), 155-174. See document online
- Grundel, H. (2010). Natural resource governance in conflict-affected contexts (Strengthening the economic dimensions of peacebuilding practice note 6). London: International Alert. See document online
- Guglielmetti, C. (2010). Measuring the business environment for entrepreneurship in fragile states (UNU-WIDER Working Paper No. 2010/14). Helsinki: United Nations University. See document online
- Gündüz, C., Klein, D. (2008). Conflict-sensitive approaches to value chain development (microReport #101). Washington, DC: USAID. See document online
- Gutierrez, E. (2011). Political settlements (Occasional paper number 4). London: Christian Aid. See document online
- Haider, H. (2009). Long-term job creation in fragile states (Helpdesk research report). Birmingham, GSDRC. See document online
- Hammond, L., Awad, M., Ibrahim Dagane, A., Hansen, P., Horst, C., Menkhaus, K., & Obare, L. (2011). Cash and compassion. The role of the Somali diaspora in relief, development and peacebuilding. New York: UNDP See document online
- Harwell, E. (2010). Forests in fragile and conflict-affected states. Washington, DC: PROFOR. See document online
- Haver, K. (2009). Self-protection in conflict: Community strategies for keeping safe in the Democratic Republic of Congo. Oxford: Oxfam.
- Hegre, H., Gissinger, R., & Gleditsch, N. P. (2002). Globalization and internal conflict. In G. Schneider, K. Barbieri & N. P. Gleditsch (Eds.), Globalization and conflict. Boulder, CO: Rowman & Littlefield. See document online
- Herbert, S. (2014). Sequencing reforms in fragile states: topic guide. Birmingham: GSDRC. See document online
- Herrendorf, B., Rogerson, R., & Valentinyi, A. (2014). Growth and structural transformation. In P. Aghion & S. N. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of economic growth (vol. 2, pp. 855-941). Amsterdam: North-Holland. See document online
- Holden, J., & Pagel, M. (2012). ‘Fragile states’ economies: What does fragility mean for economic performance? (Helpdesk request). London: EPS PEAKS. See document online
- Holmes, R., McCord, A., Hagen-Zanker, J., Bergh, G., & Zanker, F. (2013). What is the evidence on the impact of employment creation on stability and poverty reduction in fragile states: A systematic review. London: ODI. See document online
- Hudson, V. M., Ballif-Spanvill, B., Caprioli, M., & Emmett, C. F. (2008). The heart of the matter: The security of women and the security of states. International Security, 33(3), 7-45. See document online
- Hudson, V. M., Ballif-Spanvill, B., Caprioli, M., & Emmett, C. F. (2012). Sex and world peace. New York: Columbia University Press.
- Human Security Centre. (2005). Human security report 2005: War and peace in the 21st Century. New York: Oxford University Press. See document online
- Humphreys, M., & Weinstein, J. M. (2009). Field experiments and the political economy of development. Annual Review of Political Science, 12, 367-78. See document online
- Ibáñez, A. M., & Moya, A. (2009). Do conflicts create poverty traps? Asset losses and recovery for displaced households in Colombia (MICROCON Research Working Paper 10). Brighton: IDS. See document online
- ICMM. (2014). Enhancing mining’s contribution to the Zambian economy and society. London: ICMM). See document online
- Iff, A., Sguaitamatti, D, Alluri, R. M., & Kohler, D. (2010). Money makers as peace makers? Business actors in mediation processes (Working Paper Series No. 2). Bern: SwissPeace. See document online
- ILO. (2010). Local economic recovery in post-conflict: Guidelines. Geneva: ILO. See document online
- IMF. (2001). IMF concludes article IV consultation with the Democratic Republic of the Congo (PIN No. 01/70). Washington, DC: IMF. See document online
- IMF. (2007). Guide on resource revenue transparency. Washington, DC: IMF. See document online
- IMF. (2011). Macroeconomic and operational challenges in fragile situations. Washington, DC: IMF. See document online
- Institute for Economics and Peace. (2013).Pillars of peace: Understanding the key attitudes and institutions that underpin peaceful societies. Sydney: Institute for Economics and Peace. See document online
- International Alert. (2006a). Addressing the economic dimensions of peacebuilding through trade and support to private enterprise. London: International Alert. See document online
- International Alert. (2006b). Local business, local peace: The peacebuilding potential of the domestic private sector: Executive summary. London: International Alert. See document online
- Iyenda, G. (2005). Street enterprises, urban livelihoods and poverty in Kinshasa. Environment and Urbanisation, 17(2). See document online
- Jacobsen, K. (2002). Livelihoods in conflict: The pursuit of livelihoods by refugees and the impact on the human security of host communities. International Migration, 40(5), 95–123. See document online
- Jacobsen, K., Lautze, S., & Osman, A. M. K. (2001). The Sudan: The unique challenges of displacement in Khartoum. In M. Vincent & B.R. Sorensen (Eds.), Caught between borders: Response strategies of the internally displaced. Sterling, VA: Pluto.
- Jaspars, S., Maxwell, D. (2009). Food security and livelihoods programming in conflict: A review (Humanitarian Practice Network paper 65). London: ODI. See document online
- Jaspars, S., & O’Callaghan, S. (2010). Challenging choices: Protection and livelihoods in conflict: Case studies from Darfur, Chechnya, Sri Lanka and the Occupied Palestinian Territories (HPG Report 31). London: ODI. See document online
- Jones, S., & Howarth, S. (2012). Supporting infrastructure development in fragile and conflict-affected states: Learning from experience. London: DFID. See document online
- Justino, P. (2011). Violent conflict and human capital accumulation. (MICROCON Research Working Paper 54). Brighton: MICROCON.See document online
- Jyoti, R., Rai, H., Hofman, A., & Grossmann, H. (2006). Business for peace: Nepali private sector gets involved in conflict transformation and peacebuilding (GTZ Strategy Paper). Bonn: National Business Initiative.
- Kahanec, M., & Yuksel, M. (2010). Intergenerational transfer of human capital under post-war distress: The displaced and the Roma in the Former Yugoslavia (Discussion Paper 5108). Bonn: IZA. See document online
- Kangas, A., Haider,H., & Fraser, E. (with Browne, E.). (2014). GSDRC Gender Topic Guide (Revised edition). Birmingham: GSDRC. See document online
- Keen, D. (2001).Disqualifying grievance? A response to the Collier/Hoeffler model as an explanation for civil war. Presented to CODEP Conference, School of Oriental and African Studies, London, June 18-20.
- Keen, D. (2009). Economic initiatives to tackle conflict: Bringing politics back in (Occasional Paper 9). London: Crisis States Research Centre See document online
- Khan, M. (2005). What is a ‘good investment climate’? In G. Kochendorfer-Lucius & B. Pleskovic (Eds.), Investment climate, growth, and poverty. Washington, DC: World Bank. See document online
- Killick, N., Srikantha, V., & Gündüz, C. (2005). The role of local business in peacebuilding. Berlin: Berghof Research Center for Constructive Conflict Management See document online
- Kimenyi, M., Adibe, J., Djiré, M., Jirgi, A. J., Kergna, A., Deressa, T. T., … Westbury, A. (2014). The impact of conflict and political instability on agricultural investments in Mali and Nigeria (Africa Growth Initiative working paper 17). Washington, DC: Brookings See document online
- Kishor, S., & Johnson, K., (2005). Women at the nexus of poverty and violence: How unique is their disadvantage. Washington, DC: USAID. See document online
- Klare, M. T. (2001). Natural resource wars: The new landscape of global conflict. New York: Metropolitan Books. .
- Imai, K., & Weinstein, J. (2000). Measuring the economic impact of civil war (CID Working Paper No. 51). Cambridge, MA: Harvard Kennedy School. See document online
- Lautze, S., & Raven Roberts, A. (2006). Violence and complex emergencies: Implications for livelihoods models. Disasters, 30(4), 383–401 See document online
- Leo, B., Ramachandran, V., & Thuotte, R. (2012). Supporting private business growth in African fragile states: A guiding framework for the World Bank Group in South Sudan and other nations. Washington, DC: Center for Global Development See document online
- Levitt, S. D., & Venkatesh, S. A. (2000). An economic analysis of a drug-selling gang’s finances. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 755-789. See document online
- Lister, S., & Paine, A. (2004). Trading in power: The politics of ‘free’ market in Afghanistan (Briefing paper). Kabul: Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit. See document online
- Loayza, N., & Raddatz, C. (2006). The composition of growth matters for poverty alleviation (World Bank Research Working Paper 4077). Washington, DC: World Bank. See document online
- Longley, C., Christoplos, I., Slaymaker, T., & Meseka, S. (2007). Rural recovery in fragile states: Agricultural support in countries emerging from conflict (Natural Resource Perspectives 105). London: ODI. See document online
- Lyon, F., Porter, G., Adamu, F., & Obafemi, L. (2006). Nigeria case study. In J. Banfield, C. Gündüz, & N. Killick (Eds.), Local business, local peace: The peace-building potential of the domestic private sector London: International Alert. See document online
- Mac Sweeney, N. (2008). Private sector development in post-conflict countries: A review of current literature and practice. Cambridge: DCED. See document online
- Mallett, R.,& Slater, R. (2012). Growth and livelihoods in fragile and conflict-affected situations (Secure Livelihoods Research Consortium working paper 9). London: ODI. See document online
- Massa, I., & te Velde, D. W. (2011). The role of development finance institutions in tackling global challenges (Project Briefing No. 65). London: ODI See document online
- McLeod, D., & Dávalos, M. E. (2008). Postconflict employment creation for stabilisation and poverty reduction See document online
- Mcloughlin, C. (2012). Topic Guide on Fragile States. Birmingham: GSDRC. See document online
- Mejía Acosta, A. (2013). The impact and effectiveness of accountability and transparency initiatives: The governance of natural resources. Development Policy Review, 31(s1), s89–s105. See document online
- Mejía Acosta, A. (2014). The extractive industries transparency initiative: Impact, effectiveness, and where next for expanding natural resource governance? (U4 Brief No. 6). Bergen: Chr. Michelsen Institute. See document online
- Melamed, C. (2013). Economic growth and transformation in a post-2015 agreement (Background paper). London: ODI. See document online
- Mercy Corps .(2011). Peacebuilding through economic development approach. Portland, OR: Mercy Corps. See document online
- Mercy Corp. (2015). Does youth employment build stability? Evidence from an impact evaluation of vocational training in Afghanistan. Portland, OR: Mercy Corps. See document online
- Mercy Corp (n. d.). Why youth fight: Making sense of youth political violence in Sub-Saharan Africa. Portland, OR: Mercy Corps See document online
- Messer, E., Cohen, M. J. & D’Costa, J. (1998). Food from peace: Breaking the links between conflict and hunger (Food, Agriculture, and the Environment Discussion Paper 24). Washington, DC: IFPRI.
- MIGA. (2004). An evaluation of MIGA investment climate activities. Washington, DC: World Bank.
- Miguel, E., Satyanath, S., & Sergenti, E. (2004). Economic shocks and civil conflict: An instrumental variables approach. Journal of Political Economy, 112 (4), 725-753. See document online
- Mills, R., & Fan, Q. (2006). The investment climate in post-conflict situations (World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4055). Washington, DC: World Bank. See document online
- Moore, M., & Schmitz, H. (2008). Idealism, realism and the investment climate in developing countries (IDS research summary 307). Brighton: IDS. See document online
- Murshed, S. M., & Tadjoeddin, M. Z. (2009). Revisiting the greed and grievance explanations for violent internal conflict. Journal of International Development, 21(1), 87-111. See document online
- Nathan, L. (2005). ‘The frightful inadequacy of most of the statistics’: A critique of collier and hoeffler on causes of civil war (Crisis States Research Centre Discussion Papers, 11). London: LSE. See document online
- Nelson, J. (2000). The business of peace. The private sector as a partner in conflict prevention and resolution. London: International Alert. See document online
- Nenova, T., & Harford, T. (2004). Anarchy and invention. How does Somalia’s private sector cope without government? (Public Policy for the Private Sector, Note number 280). Washington, DC: World Bank. See document online
- O’Callaghan, S., Jaspars, S., & Pavanello, S. (2009) Losing ground: Protection and livelihoods in the occupied Palestinian territories (HPG Working Paper). London: ODI. See document online
- Ockenden, A. (2011). Opposing the motion ‘The M4P approach has limited utility in post-conflict environments’ (M4P Hub Debate Discussion Paper). Reading: M4P Hub. See document online
- OECD. (2009). Ensuring fragile states are not left behind (Summary Report). Paris: OECD. See document online
- OECD-DAC. (2008). State-building in situations of fragility: Initial findings. Paris: OECD. See document online
- OECD-DAC. (2010). International support to statebuilding in situations of fragility and conflict. See document online
- Ostby, G. (2008). Inequalities, the political environment and civil conflict: Evidence from 55 developing countries. In F. Stewart (Ed.), Horizontal inequalities and conflict: Understanding group violence in multiethnic societies (pp. 136-159). Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
- Pantuliano, S., & Elhawary, S. (2009). Uncharted territory: Land, conflict and humanitarian action (HPG Policy Brief 39). London: ODI. See document online
- Pantuliano, S., Buchanan-Smith, M., Metcalfe, V., Pavanello, S., & Martin, E. (2011). City limits: Urbanisation and vulnerability in Sudan (HPG Synthesis Report). London: ODI. See document online
- Parker, J. (2008). A synthesis of practical lessons from value chain projects in conflict-affected environments (microReport #105). Washington, DC: USAID. See document online
- Pellillo, A. (2012). Conflict and development: Evidence from the Democratic Republic of the Congo. See document online
- Peschka, M. P. (2011). The role of the private sector in fragile and conflict-affected states (World Development Report background paper). Washington, DC: World Bank. See document online
- Petesch, P. (2011). Women’s empowerment arising from violent conflict and recovery. Washington, DC: USAID See document online
- Petesch, P. (2012). The clash of violent conflict, good jobs, and gender norms in four economies (World Development Report background paper). Washington, DC: World Bank. See document online
- Polachek, S., & Sevastianova, D. (2010). Does conflict disrupt growth? Evidence of the relationship between political instability and national economic performance (IZA Discussion Paper No. 4762). Bonn: IZA. See document online
- Polachek, S., Seigle, C., & Xiang, J. (2012). Globalization and international conflict: Can FdI increase peace? In M. R. Garfinkel & S. Skaperdas (Eds.), Oxford handbook of the economics of peace and conflict. Oxford: Oxford University Press. See document online
- Pugh, M. (2008). Employment, labour rights and social resistance. In M. Pugh, N. Copper, & M. Turner (Eds.), Whose peace? Critical perspectives on the political economy of peace-building (pp. 139-56). Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillam.
- Raeymaekers, T. (2006). Conflict and food security in Beni-Lubero. Rome: FAO. See document online
- Raeymaekers, T. (2011). Forced displacement and youth employment in the aftermath of the Congo war: From making a living to making a life (MICROCON Research Working Paper 38). Brighton: IDS. See document online
- Raniere, R., & Ramos, R. (2013). Inclusive growth: Building up a concept (Working Paper number 104). Brasilia: International Policy Centre for Inclusive Growth. See document online
- Rao, S. (2010). Investment climate in fragile and conflict affected states (Helpdesk Report). Birmingham: GSDRC. See document online
- Rockmore, M. (2011). The cost of fear: The welfare effects of the risk of violence in Northern Uganda (HiCN Working Paper 109). Brighton: IDS. See document online
- Ross, M. L. (2003). Oil, drugs, and diamonds: The varying roles of natural resources in civil war. In K. Ballentine & J. Sherman (Eds.), The political economy of armed conflict: Beyond greed and grievance (pp. 47-70). Boulder: Lynne Rienner. See document online
- Salazar-Xirinachs, J. M., Nubler, I., & Kozul-Wright, R. (2014). Industrial policy, productive transformation and jobs: Theory, history and practice. In J. M. Salazar-Xirinachs, I. Nubler, & R. Kozul-Wright, Transforming Economies: Making industrial policy work for growth, jobs and development (pp. 1-40). Geneva: ILO. See document online
- Saperstein, A., & Campbell, R. (2008). Accelerating the transition from conflict to sustainable growth: Value chain development in conflict-affected environments (microREPORT #101). Washington DC: USAID. See document online
- Seddon, D., & Hussein, K. (2002). The consequences of conflict: Livelihoods and development in Nepal (Livelihoods and Chronic Conflict Working Paper 185). London: ODI. See document online
- SEEP Network. (2007). Market development in crisis-affected environments: Emerging lessons for achieving pro-poor economic reconstruction. Washington, DC: SEEP Network. See document online
- Shemyakina, O. (2006). The effect of armed conflict on accumulation of schooling: Results from Tajikistan (HiCN Working Paper 12). Brighton: IDS. See document online
- Sinha, S., Holmberg, J. & Thomas, M. (2013). What works for market development: a review of the evidence. UTV Working Paper 1. See document online
- Slim, H. (2012). Business actors in armed conflict: Towards a new Humanitarian agenda. International Review of the Red Cross, 94(887). See document online
- Sperling, L., & McGuire, S. (2010) .‘Persistent myths about emergency seed aid. Food Policy, 35, 195-201. See document online
- Stewart, F. (2002). Horizontal inequalities: A neglected dimension of development (QEH Working Paper Number 81). Oxford: Queen Elizabeth House. See document online
- Stewart, F. (2010). Horizontal inequalities as a cause of conflict: A review of CRISE findings (World Development Report 2011 Background Paper). Washington, DC: World Bank. See document online
- Suhrke, A., & Buckmaster, J. (2006). Aid, growth and peace: a comparative analysis. Conflict, Security & Development, 6(3), 337-363. See document online
- Tyler, A. (2008). Protection and livelihoods in Somalia. Humanitarian Exchange Magazine, 40.. See document online
- UNDG. (2013). Natural resource management in transition settings (UNDG-ECHA Guidance Note). New York: UN. See document online
- UNDP. (2008). Crisis prevention and recovery report 2008: Post-conflict economic recovery, enabling local ingenuity. New York: UNDP. See document online
- United Nations. (2007). What is peacebuilding? In( Application guidelines. New York: UN. See document online
- United Nations. (2009a). United Nations policy for post-conflict employment generation, income generation and reintegration. New York: UN. See document online
- United Nations. (2009b). Post-conflict employment creation, income generation and reintegration: Operational guidance note. New York: UN. See document online
- United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs. (2004). Expert group meeting on conflict prevention, peacebuilding and development: Issues paper for the session on natural resource governance and conflict prevention. New York: UN. See document online
- United Nations Environment Programme. (2009). From conflict to peacebuilding – The role of natural resources and the environment. New York: UNEP. See document online
- United Nations Environment Programme, United Nations Entity for Gender Equality and the Empowerment of Women, United Nations Peacebuilding Support Office, & United Nations Development Programme. (2013). Women and natural resources unlocking the peacebuilding potential. New York:UN See document online
- United Nations Interagency Framework Team for Preventative Action. (2012). Strengthening capacity for conflict-sensitive natural resource management (Toolkit and Guidance for Preventing and Managing Land and Natural Resources Conflict). New York: UN. See document online
- UNODC. (2009). Afghanistan opium survey 2009: Summary findings. New York: UN. See document online
- USAID. (2009). A guide to economic growth in post-conflict countries. Washington, DC: USAID. See document online
- USAID. (2010). A rough guide to investment climate reform in conflict-affected countries. Washington, DC: USAID. See document online
- USAID, & DFID. (2014). Bangladesh: Inclusive growth diagnostic. Washington, DC and London: USAID and DFID. See document online
- USIP. (2008). Conflict-sensitive approach to infrastructure development. Washington, DC: United States Institute of Peace. See document online
- Von Luebke, C., McCulloch, N., Patunru, A., & Wardhani, S. B. (2009). Heterodox reform symbioses: The political economy of investment climate reforms in Solo, Indonesia. Asian Economic Journal, 23(3), 269-296. See document online
- Walton, O. (2010a). Improving the investment climate in FCAS (Helpdesk research report). Birmingham: GSDRC. See document online
- Walton, O. (2010b). Evidence for the supporting investment climate in FCAS (Helpdesk research report). Birmingham: GSDRC. See document online
- Walton, O. (2010c). Youth, armed violence and job creation programmes: A rapid mapping study. Birmingham: GSDRC See document online
- Whaites, A. (2008). States in development: Understanding state-building (DFID Working Paper). London: DFID. See document online
- Krug, E. G., Dahlberg, L. L., Mercy, J. A., Zwi, A. B., & Lozano, R. (2002). World report on violence and health. Geneva: WHO. See document online
- Women’s Refugee Commission. (2008). Youth and sustainable livelihoods: Linking vocational training programmes to market opportunities in Northern Uganda. New York: Women’s Refugee Commission. See document online
- World Bank. (2007). Global monitoring report: Millennium development goals: Confronting the challenges of gender equality and fragile states. Washington, DC: World Bank. See document online
- World Bank. (2009). What is inclusive growth? Washington, DC: World Bank See document online
- World Bank. (2011). World development report: Conflict, security, and development. Washington, DC: World Bank.
- World Bank. (2014). Public-private dialogue in fragile and conflict-affected situations: Experiences and lessons learned. Washington, DC: World Bank. See document online
- Wright, H., & Tielemans, S. (2014). Gender, violence and peace. A post-2015 development agenda. Saferworld & Conciliation Resources See document online
- Yusuf, A. W. (2006). Somali enterprises: Making peace their business. In International Alert local business, local peace: The peace-building potential of the domestic private sector. London: International Alert. See document online